From time to time, or actually rather seldom, ones
research may become relevant for real political events. With the impeachment
threat looming over President Dilma Rouseff, some observers have revisited some
of the arguments I made with Einar Berntzen in our article in Comparative
Politics in 2008. In that article we study and categorise the many presidential
breakdowns in Latin America.
Taking as point of departure Juan Linz's thesis that presidential regimes are not as well equipped as parliamentary regimes to tackle political conflicts, we argue that the presidential breakdowns rather show that presidential regimes in solving their crises seem to have overcome its deficiensies. The perils of presidentialism according to Linz were rigidity due to the fixed terms of parliament and president, and dual democratic legitimacy since both parliament and president enjoy direct democratic legitimacy. These problems make it difficult to solve conflicts between parliament and president since it is difficult to remove either institution democratically, and there is no institution that by definition decides over the other. In parliamentarism conflicts are solved by parliament (or its majority) having the power to nominate and remove the government, and the government normally, and within some set limits, has the power to call for early elections.
The article then argues that the removal of presidents
before the end of the electoral term demonstrates that the fixed terms are not
as fixed as we believed, and that instead of ending in democratic breakdowns,
which Linz predicted, conflicts in presidential regimes in Latin America now
end in presidential breakdown with democracy surviving. We further argued that
some of these presidential falls resemble parliamentary modes of conflict
resolution. Whereas we argued that impeachment was a presidential form of
conflict resolution, since impeachment of the president is constitutionalised
in most presidential regimes in Latin America, we said that other forms of
parliament voting out the president resembled votes of no confidence. Types of
this could be votes of incapacity, or abandonment of the presidency. The cases
were here two in Ecuador (1997 and 2005), and one in Bolivia (in 2005), the
latter being an example of a president losing a vote of confidence which led to
presidential resignation, in addition to failed attempts such as in Peru in
1991. We further pointed to another aspect, which was the call for early
elections during times of crisis as another sign of choosing parliamentary
solutions to presidential crises. This latter aspect has often gone unnoticed.
We counted (back in 2008) early elections in Bolivia (twice), Dominican
Republic, Argentina and Peru. In the article Einar Berntzen and I interpreted
rather positively these presidential breakdowns (or interrupted presidencies as
we call them) since they did not end in democratic breakdown, and we argued
that the flexible solutions (not always envisioned constitutionally at the
time) had helped avoid full democratic breakdown.
After our article, the use of impeachment has gone
from only dealing with unconstitutional and undemocratic behaviour (Raúl Cubas
in Paraguay in 1999) and corruption, to seemingly deal with more strictly
political matters in the case of President Lugo in 2012, and Dilma Rouseff in
Brazil today. With Mariana Llanos and Detlef Nolte, we analysed the fall of
President Lugo highlighting the aspect of the politics of impeachment. In this
case Lugo did not fall because he was corrupt, but because 2/3 of Congress
argued he did not perform his duties well. Using political motives to spur an
impeachment process could then also make impeachment procedures resemble a type
of vote of no confidence used in parliamentary regimes, and one could argue
that impeachment was used "parliamentary-style". In Brazil today, it
also seems that impeachment is much more politically motivated than in the case
of for instance Collor in 1992 (a case of corruption), and therefore many have
argued that impeachment is not warranted in this case. Again we see impeachment
used as a vote of no confidence, but with a 2/3 bar rather than 1/2.
Pérez-Liñán revisited the parliamentarisation arguments in an article in La Nación where
he pointed out, correctly, that an impeachment is not a vote of no confidence,
and this is also one reason the current efforts to impeach Dilma have been
criticised. Originally, as I mentioned, we never thought of impeachment as a
form of vote of no confidence, or parliamentarisation, but in the cases of Lugo
and Dilma impeachment resembles votes of no-confidence. As such these two cases may strengthen our original
argument that presidential regimes copy parliamentary regimes when solving
conflicts, even though impeachment as vote of no-confidence may be harder to
defend normatively for the very reasons Pérez-Liñán mentions (but is still better than our the alternative outcomes provisioned in the literature we discussed in our article: democratic breakdown). At any rate it is
interesting to observe that presidentialism as we thought it, is evolving even
though we may disagree with its direction. (For pragmatic reasons, however, I
find that if a 2/3 majority in both chambers are willing to remove the
president I think they should be allowed to do so no matter the reason. This is
simply because if 2/3 of the representatives want the president removed, the
president is most likely not able to govern anyway and her/his survival may then
secure un-governability. A new president, all else equal, should have a higher probability of obtaining congressional majorities).
But, if we are to revisit the flexibilisation or parliamentarisation argument for the current crisis in Brazil, I much rather suggest considering one of the parliamentary formula we actually discussed: that of holding early elections (for congress and president). Early elections, however, is not envisioned constitutionally, and requires constitutional reform. Further, parliamentarians are not known for voting in favour of something that will leave them without (a well-paid) job. The solution is therefore maybe unlikely, but one could promise parliamentarians immunity in exchange for early elections, which would increase parliamentarians' incentives. Early elections instead of just impeaching Dilma has the benefit of sharing the blame equally between parliament and president which seems on the face of it more just in the case at hand (because in Brazil no one is without sin even though everyone casts stones). Several observers, including The Economist, have already suggested it, and it seems a somewhat more just solution than putting all blame on Dilma.
But, if we are to revisit the flexibilisation or parliamentarisation argument for the current crisis in Brazil, I much rather suggest considering one of the parliamentary formula we actually discussed: that of holding early elections (for congress and president). Early elections, however, is not envisioned constitutionally, and requires constitutional reform. Further, parliamentarians are not known for voting in favour of something that will leave them without (a well-paid) job. The solution is therefore maybe unlikely, but one could promise parliamentarians immunity in exchange for early elections, which would increase parliamentarians' incentives. Early elections instead of just impeaching Dilma has the benefit of sharing the blame equally between parliament and president which seems on the face of it more just in the case at hand (because in Brazil no one is without sin even though everyone casts stones). Several observers, including The Economist, have already suggested it, and it seems a somewhat more just solution than putting all blame on Dilma.
Another criticism of the impeachment solution is that
the removal of the president in Dilma's case will not solve much. I agree. This has
to do with the type of crisis in Brazil. Should Dilma fall the lava jato
scandal and investigation will still be there, and more importantly the poor
economic performance will not automatically go away with Dilma. In another article on the topic I point out that presidential breakdown
- the early removal of the president - seemed to have worked well (that is
stabilising the political situation and avoiding more breakdowns) when the crisis is related mainly to the
person inhabiting the presidency (for instance corruption in the case of Collor).
Then you "solve" the problem by removing the president, and people protesting
in the streets go home. Presidential breakdown also seems to have worked well
when the president has been of the semi-authoritarian type such as Fujimori in
Peru or Balaguer in the Dominican Republic. Again the motive for people going
into the streets is removed with the removal of the president, and in these
cases removing the president also holds the benefit of democratising the country (Venezuela today could become a similar case). However, when the
problems have been political and/or economic, or both, such as in Ecuador and Bolivia in
the early 2000s, and in Brazil today, then removing the president does not
solve all that much (even though democratic breakdown has been avoided). The underlying problems persist, people will come out in the
streets again, and often instability continues (think Bolivia and Ecuador in
the years before Morales and Correa took over). Things tend to stabilise first
after a new president implementing a policy switch have come into power. This
occurred right away in Bolivia in the 1980s with Paz Estenssoro and also in
Argentina with Menem (no more presidential falls), but took some time and some more presidential falls in
Bolivia and Ecuador in the 2000s.
Taking lessons from these more politically motivated
presidential breakdowns we find that a potential successor to Dilma may quickly
also be in peril unless he manages to drastically change the political and
economic course of the country in a manner that sufficiently satisfies people and encourages them to home rather than taking to the streets.
Some of my articles on the topic
Marsteintredet,
Leiv (2014). Explaining variation of executive instability in
presidential regimes: Presidential interruptions in Latin America. International
Political Science Review. ISSN 0192-5121. 35(2), s 173- 194
.
Marsteintredet,
Leiv, Mariana Llanos & Detlef Nolte. 2013. Paraguay and the
Politics of Impeachment. In Journal of Democracy 24(4),
October (pp.110-123).
Marsteintredet,
Leiv & Einar Berntzen (2008). Reducing the Perils of Presidentialism in
Latin America through Presidential Interruptions. In Comparative Politics
41(1), October (pp. 83-101).
The electoral process is expensive Brazil. Legislators tend to prepare for the elections accumulating legal and illegal resources. To provide immunity does not solve the problem of a sudden election, introducing more uncertainty than normal for them.
SvarSlett